Discussion about this post

User's avatar
The Mont Pelerin Review's avatar

1. You're half right about inflation being a monetary phenomenon à la Friedman. The Fed can counter fiscal deficits with tight monetary policy, as it did in the early 1980s. However, the stimulus still fueled a significant portion of the demand-driven inflation. This New York Fed paper estimates that at least half of the post-pandemic demand-side inflation can be attributed to fiscal stimulus: https://www.newyorkfed.org/medialibrary/media/research/staff_reports/sr1050.pdf

2. Here's how I would approach countercyclical policy. On the monetary side, implement an NGDP target or Taylor Rule. On the fiscal side, implement a Swiss debt rule, which means that Congress can run deficits during recessions but must run surpluses and reduce debt over the entire business cycle.

3. What are your thoughts on static vs. dynamic scoring? Republicans argue the CBO should account for the pro-growth effects of tax cuts. Democrats respond that the CBO should also include the growth impacts of things like infrastructure spending. Both sides have a point. But in my view, dynamic scoring is difficult to do with precision, and we should be very wary of budget gimmicks. However, the dynamic impact of tax cuts or spending hikes that increase the deficit seems relevant to your NPV fiscal rule.

Expand full comment
Laurence Mailaender's avatar

Thomas, my understanding is that the ‘level’ of spending is important, but so is WHAT it’s spent on. Government spending that increases supply (improved ports, roads, loans for capital assets…) should not cause long term inflation. Can you comment?

Expand full comment
21 more comments...

No posts